Skip to main content

The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

Measuring the comprehensive wage effect of changes in unit labor cost

Abstract

Unit labor cost (ULC) is defined as labor compensation per value added. It captures the cost competitiveness of industries and countries. As labor compensation is wage multiplied by hours worked or number of people employed, it is easy to show that ULC is wage divided by labor productivity. Thus, changes in ULC are often discussed in the context of wage increases and labor productivity. However, a higher wage induces firms to substitute labor with capital, which affects labor productivity. However, the conventional decomposition of changes in ULC dismisses this indirect impact of wage on ULC through labor productivity. We propose an alternative decomposition of the change in ULC with a measure of a comprehensive wage effect, which fully captures its direct as well as indirect impact. It allows us to understand more accurately the role of wage changes in enhancing cost competitiveness. Furthermore, we compare measures of the wage effect under two decompositions, using data from 18 OECD countries over the 1995–2005 period. We find the wage effect to be significantly overestimated under the conventional decomposition. This study looks at ULC for the whole country as well as for two sectors—manufacturing sector and electricity, gas, and water supply sector.

JEL Classification: C43, D24, O47, E31

1 Background

Unit labor cost (ULC) is defined as labor compensation per unit of value added.Footnote 1 As it captures labor cost required to produce one unit of value added, it is widely accepted as an appropriate measure of cost competitiveness for a producer.Footnote 2 ULC is often computed for industries and countries. Monitoring it over a period or across units helps one to track their cost competitiveness.

While labor compensation is units of labor multiplied by labor compensation per unit of labor (simply wage), the value added divided by units of labor defines labor productivity.Footnote 3 Thus, ULC can be considered the ratio of wage to labor productivity. A change in the ULC is often attributed to a change in the wage (wage effect) and in labor productivity (labor productivity effect). This suggests that there are two ways of enhancing cost competitiveness: retaining wage or raising labor productivity. This conventional decomposition of the change or difference in ULC into two effects has been applied to investigate the sources of cost competitiveness for industries or countries.Footnote 4 Van Ark et al. (2005) compare the ULC of the manufacturing sector for OECD member countries. They indicated that even among advanced economies, there are significant differences between countries in terms of the relative contributions of the wage and labor productivity effects.Footnote 5 , Footnote 6

However, the current decomposition of the changes in ULC has shortcomings. These arise from the fact that wage and labor productivity are not independently determined. Faced with input prices such as user cost of capital and wage, a firm’s demand for capital and labor is such that production cost is minimized. Thus, a rise in wage induces a firm to employ more capital and hire less labor. As Mizobuchi (2014) emphasizes, this is likely to raise labor productivity, holding other factors constant. Thus, the labor productivity effect in a conventional decomposition is partly attributable to wage changes. In other words, this indirect impact of a wage change through labor productivity is not captured by the current measure of the wage effect.

This study proposes an alternative decomposition of changes in the ULC into three components; these are two factor-price effects (user cost of capital and wage) and a technical change effect. First, we define each component theoretically using a ULC function. Second, we derive index number formulae that approximate each component. The wage effect in this decomposition captures fully the impact of a change in wages on the ULC. Its direct impact on labor compensation as well as its indirect impact through a change in labor productivity is captured. We show that the bias in the conventional measure of wage effect depends on production technology, especially output elasticity or factor shares.

We apply our decomposition to data from 18 OECD countries by employing EU KLEMS. We focus on the period 1995–2006, for which data is available for the largest number of countries. For each country, we decompose the ULC of the whole country, manufacturing sector, and electricity, gas, and water supply sector. This allows us to quantify empirically by how much the conventional measure of wage effect overestimates or underestimates the comprehensive impact on ULC of wage changes. Since the underlying technology varies across sectors, the magnitude of bias in the conventional wage effect is also likely to vary.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 decomposes the change in ULC into three components. Section 3 applies this decomposition to data from OECD countries. Section 4 concludes the paper.

2 Methods

We introduce a simple model of production to incorporate substitution between capital and labor. A firm utilizes capital K and labor L to produce a single output, Y. We assume the firm’s cost-minimizing behavior. Thus, given output Y, a firm chooses K and L to minimize cost based on factor prices r (user cost of capital) and w (wage). Technology at period t is represented by the production function Y = F t(K, L), which exhibits constant returns to scale. Given factor prices and output, the period t cost function of a firm is as follows:

$$ {C}^t\left(r,w,Y\right)= \max \left\{rK+wL:Y={F}^t\left(K,L\right)\right\} $$
(1)

Since we assume constant-returns-to-scale technology, the cost function is a multiplication of the unit cost function and output, such as C t(r, w, Y) = C t(r, w, 1) ⋅ Y. Applying Shephard’s lemma (Shephard 1970), we derive the following unit labor cost function as the function of factor prices and time:

$$ {\mathrm{ULC}}^t\left(r,w\right)=\frac{w\cdot \partial {C}^t\left(r,w,Y\right)/\partial w}{Y}=w\cdot \partial {C}^t\left(r,w,1\right)/\partial w $$
(2)

This is the key equation for determining changes in ULC. Let us compare ULC for two periods, 0 and 1. First, we look at the comprehensive impact of the change in wage on the ULC. The wage effect is measured by the ratio ULCt(r, w 1)/ULCt(r, w 0). It indicates the change in ULC induced by the change in wage going from period 0 to 1, using the technology that is available during the reference period t and facing the reference user cost of capital, r. Since each choice of the reference vector (t, r) might generate a different measure, we calculate two measures using different reference vectors (0, r 0) and (1, r 1) which, in fact, are observed in each period and thus are equally reasonable. Then, following Fisher (1922) and Diewert (1976), we use the geometric mean of these measures as a theoretical measure of the wage effect, Wage, as follows:

$$ \mathrm{Wage}=\sqrt{\frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^0,{w}^1\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^0,{w}^0\right)}\cdot \frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^1,{w}^1\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^1,{w}^0\right)}} $$
(3)

Second, we consider the comprehensive impact of the change in user cost of capital on ULC. The user cost effect is measured by the ratio ULCt(r 1, w)/ULCt(r 0, w). It indicates the change in ULC induced by the change in user cost going from period 0 to 1, using the technology that is available during the reference period t and facing the reference wage, w. As each choice of the reference vector (s, w) might generate a different measure, we calculate two measures using different reference vectors (0, w 0) and (1, w 1) which, in fact, are observed in each period and thus are equally reasonable. Then, we use the geometric mean of these measures as a theoretical measure of user cost effect, User cost, as follows:

$$ \mathrm{User}\ \mathrm{cost}=\sqrt{\frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^1,{w}^0\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^0,{w}^0\right)}\cdot \frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^1,{w}^1\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^0,{w}^1\right)}} $$
(4)

Lastly, we consider the impact of a technical change on the ULC. Technical change is measured by the ratio ULC1(r, w)/ULC0(r, w). It indicates the change in ULC induced by technical change going from period 0 to 1, facing the reference factor prices r and w. Since each choice of the reference vector (r, w) might generate a different measure, we calculate two measures using different reference vectors (r 0, w 0) and (r 1, w 1) which, in fact, are observed in each period and thus are equally reasonable. Then, we use the geometric mean of these measures as a theoretical measure of technical change effect, Technology, as follows:

$$ \mathrm{Technology}=\sqrt{\frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^0,{w}^0\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^0,{w}^0\right)}\cdot \frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^1,{w}^1\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^1,{w}^1\right)}} $$
(5)

These three measures are theoretical ones. Thus, even though we know the factor prices prevailing at each period, we cannot compute these measures, which are defined by the unknown ULC functions. There are multiple ways of implementing these measures. Here, we adopt the index number approach and derive the index number formula that approximates the theoretical measures proposed above. Our purpose is to propose a tractable way of investigating the sources of the change in ULC, replacing the conventional decomposition.Footnote 7

We implement them by assuming the following production functions for t = 0, 1:

$$ {F}^t\left(K,L\right)={A}^t{K}^{\alpha^t}{L}^{\left(1-{\alpha}^t\right)} $$
(6)

It is a variant of the Cobb–Douglas production function allowing output elasticity of capital α, which is known to be equal to capital share, to vary in each period. Technology of a firm in period t is represented by a combination of A t and α t. Under this specification, the three theoretical measures coincide with a formula for factor input prices and quantities observed at two periods 0 and 1 as followsFootnote 8:

$$ \mathrm{Wage}={\left(\frac{w^1}{w^0}\right)}^{\frac{1}{2}\left({s}_L^0+{s}_L^1\right)} $$
(7)
$$ \mathrm{User}\ \mathrm{cost}={\left(\frac{r^1}{r^0}\right)}^{\frac{1}{2}\left({s}_K^0+{s}_K^1\right)} $$
(8)
$$ \mathrm{Technology}=\left(\left(\frac{w^1{L}^1}{Y^1}\right)/\left(\frac{w^0{L}^0}{Y^0}\right)\right)/\left({\left(\frac{w^1}{w^0}\right)}^{\frac{1}{2}\left({s}_L^0+{s}_L^1\right)}\times {\left(\frac{r^1}{r^0}\right)}^{\frac{1}{2}\left({s}_K^0+{s}_K^1\right)}\right) $$
(9)

where \( {s}_K^t=\frac{r^t{K}^t}{\left({r}^t{K}^t+{w}^t{L}^t\right)} \) and \( {s}_L^t=\frac{w^t{L}^t}{\left({r}^t{K}^t+{w}^t{L}^t\right)} \) are the capital and labor compensation share defined for t = 0, 1.

Our measure of the wage effect is smaller than the conventional measure of wage effect w 1/w 0. A higher wage directly increases the ULC by raising the labor compensation. However, it induces a firm to substitute labor by employing more capital. Less labor raises labor productivity, lowering the ULC. Thus, the direct impact of a wage increase on labor compensation is somewhat mitigated. That is what the measure of wage effect proposed by this study incorporates. Three measures are independently proposed to capture the distinct effect on the ULC. Under the assumption of Eq. (6), the change in ULC is completely decomposed into these factors, as follows:

$$ \frac{{\mathrm{ULC}}^1\left({r}^1,{w}^1\right)}{{\mathrm{ULC}}^0\left({r}^0,{w}^0\right)}=\left(\frac{w^1{L}^1}{Y^1}\right)/\left(\frac{w^0{L}^0}{Y^0}\right)=\mathrm{Wage}\times \mathrm{User}\ \mathrm{cost}\times \mathrm{Technology} $$
(10)

Under this decomposition, labour productivity effect is captured by \( User\ cost\times Technology=\left(\left(\frac{w^1{L}^1}{Y^1}\right),/,\left(\frac{w^0{L}^0}{Y^0}\right)\right)/\left({\left(\frac{w^1}{w^0}\right)}^{\frac{1}{2}\left({s}_L^0+{s}_L^1\right)}\right) \), which contrast the conventional measure of labour productivity effect \( \left(\left(\frac{w^1{L}^1}{Y^1}\right),/,\left(\frac{w^0{L}^0}{Y^0}\right)\right)/\left(\frac{w^1}{w^0}\right)=\left(\frac{L^1}{Y^1}\right)/\left(\frac{L^0}{Y^0}\right) \).

3 Results and discussion

The data source of this study is the EU KLEMS database based on ISIC Rev. 3, which was updated in March 2011. It comprehensively covers inputs and outputs for the detailed 72 industries. We use data series of value added, capital services, and labor services for our simple case of two inputs and one output. Nominal values and volume measures of value added, capital services, and labor are available. Volume measures of these series correspond to quantities Y, K, and L, whereas input prices r and w are implicitly derived from nominal values and volume measures. We deal with the whole economy and two sectors—manufacturing sector and electricity, gas, and water supply sector among the detailed 72 industries. We intend to show empirically the bias in the current measure of wage effect and the biases varying across sectors characterized by different production technologies. We focus on the period 1995–2006, for which data necessary for computing index number formulae is available for the largest number of 18 countries.

Table 1 summarizes input–output data for the whole economy and two sectors in 18 countries for 1995–2006. GDP, which is the value added for the whole economy, grew at an average annual rate of 2.91 % in the sample countries.Footnote 9 Labor for the whole economy also increased, but its growth rate was not as much as that of GDP. In contrast, manufacturing showed a higher growth rate with a value added of 3.16 %, even with declining quantity of labor. While the value added of the electricity, gas, and water supply sector grew at a relatively low rate of 1.56 % per year, labor in this sector also declined. Thus, it indicates that labor productivity grew in the whole economy as well as the two sectors and that the growth rate was especially higher in manufacturing. Similarly, large increases in wages were also documented in the whole economy and the two sectors, where wages grew at around 4 % on average per year. It is worth noting the differences in production structures reflected by factor shares for the two sectors. While manufacturing showed a capital share of approximately 40 %, which is close to the whole economy, the electricity, gas, and water supply sector showed especially large capital share of 66.38 %, reflecting its dependence on large infrastructure.

Table 1 Average growth rate of GDP, labor and factor prices, and average share of factor input, 1995–2006 (%)

Decomposition of the changes in ULC based on Eqs. (7)–(10) is summarized in Table 2. It also presents the conventional decomposition into changes in wage and labor productivity, for comparison.Footnote 10 ULC for the whole economy significantly increased at an average rate of 2.33 % per year. On the other hand, while ULC for electricity, gas, and water supply increased at a smaller rate of 1.42 % on average per year, ULC for manufacturing was nearly constant over this period. Thus, it shows that only the manufacturing sector could hold its cost competitiveness over this period, along with other factors deteriorating their competitiveness.

Table 2 Decomposition of changes in unit labor cost, 1995–2006 (%)

Now, we investigate the sources of changes in ULC. We begin by revisiting the conventional decomposition; the large wage effect of around 4 % dominates the increase in ULC, but it is partly mitigated by labor productivity growth. Since the rate of wage increases is comparable among sectors, the difference in ULC growth can be attributed to the difference in labor productivity growth. However, once we use the alternative decomposition proposed in this study, we find that the wage effect has shrunk in the whole economy and in the two sectors, reflecting the firm’s substitution of labor by capital under higher wages. As Eq. (7) suggests, the smaller the labor share or the larger the capital share, the more the wage effect has shrunk, under the alternative measure of wage effect. Reflecting its large capital share, the electricity, gas, and water supply sector shows the largest gap in the two wage effects, falling from 4.03 % under the conventional measure to 1.42 % in the alternative decomposition.

The wage effect under the alternative decomposition proposed by this study turns out to be very close to the growth rate of ULC for the whole economy and electricity, gas, and water supply sector on average over time. Effects of user cost and technical change offset each other in these two sectors.Footnote 11 Thus, we can conclude that the long-run impact of labor productivity growth, which is induced by factors other than wage, is negligible in these sectors.

Figure 1 compares the time series of two wage effects and ULC. Evidently, there is a one-to-one relationship between the movement of ULC and the wage effect in the alternative decomposition for the whole economy. As Fig. 1 suggests, this relationship does not necessarily hold, especially in sectors where there is much technical progress. However, it is clear that the wage effect in the decomposition proposed here becomes much closer to the growth rate of ULC compared with the conventional measure of wage effect, by reducing the role of labor productivity growth, which is characterized by the joint effects of user cost change and technical change.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Comparison of two measures of wage effect and the growth rate of ULC, 1996-2006 (%)

4 Conclusions

We propose the decomposition of the change in ULC into two factor-price effects and a technical change effect. All these effects are defined by the underlying ULC function, which reflects a firm’s cost-minimizing behavior. Thus, the wage effect in our decomposition not only captures its direct impact on labor compensation but also incorporates the indirect impact on ULC through the change in labor productivity induced by wage changes. We theoretically show that the bias in the conventional measure of wage effect depends on factor shares.

The empirical examination of 18 OECD member countries indicates that the impact of the wage effect on the change in ULC is overestimated by more than one percentage point under the conventional measure of wage effect. The bias in the conventional measure is especially large for industries with large capital shares such as in the electricity, gas, and water supply sector. We find that once the comprehensive impact of wage change is appropriately measured based on the decomposition proposed in this study, the wage effect becomes smaller and much closer to the growth rate of ULC. For the whole economy, the change in ULC is almost completely explained by the wage effect.

This study is a first step towards measuring the comprehensive impact of a wage change on ULC. One limitation is clearly our selection of the functional form. Our theoretical result indicates that some index number formulae are exact to the theoretical measures based on the ULC function under the assumption of the Cobb–Douglas production function. However, even though output elasticities are allowed to vary over time, it is constant within a period. This leads to a unitary elasticity of substitution between capital and input. Thus, the assumption of Cobb–Douglas severely restricts substitution between two inputs a priori. Ideally, the exactness should hold under flexible functional forms such as the translog functional form, which imposes the minimum on the underlying production technology.Footnote 12 However, we leave the search for such superlative index number formulae of the comprehensive wage effect for ULC change to future research.

Notes

  1. Strictly speaking, we are talking about value added at constant prices or the quantity of value added.

  2. Turner and Van’t dack (1993) and Turner and Golub (1997) recommend the use of unit labor cost in manufacturing as a measure of competitiveness.

  3. Formally, \( \mathrm{U}\mathrm{L}\mathrm{C}=\frac{\mathrm{labour}\ \mathrm{compensation}}{\mathrm{value}\ \mathrm{added}}=\frac{\mathrm{wage}\times \mathrm{units}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{labour}}{\mathrm{value}\ \mathrm{added}}=\frac{\mathrm{wage}}{\mathrm{value}\ \mathrm{added}/\mathrm{units}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{labour}}=\frac{\mathrm{wage}}{\mathrm{labour}\ \mathrm{productivity}} \).

  4. As the changes in ULC over time is decomposed into changes in wage and labor productivity, the differences in ULC across units are decomposed into differences in wage and labor productivity.

  5. Although the rapidly growing share of China’s manufacturing export is often ascribed to its low wages, Ceglowski and Golub (2007, 2012) document that labor productivity growth played a significant role in lowering ULC, although this slowed down after 2003.

  6. ULC is also a key variable for estimating the New Keynesian price equation (GalĂ­ and Gertler 1999; Sbordone 2002). In these studies, real ULC, which is ULC deflated by output price, is considered a measure of marginal cost.

  7. Estimating the cost function is one way of implementing theoretical measures (see Coelli et al. 2005). However, there are multiple concerns about adopting this approach, such as the number of observations as well as specification of the stochastic term. It is far more demanding than computing the rate of wage change and labor productivity growth. Our approach is as tractable as the current decomposition.

  8. Under the specification of Eq. (6), it can be shown that \( \mathrm{U}\mathrm{L}\mathrm{C}=\frac{1}{A^t}{\left(\frac{1-{\alpha}^t}{\alpha^t}\right)}^{\alpha^t}{r}^{\alpha^t}{w}^{1-{\alpha}^t} \). Equations (7)–(9) flow from this equation.

  9. See Appendix; Tables 3, 4, and 5 for underlying country-specific data.

  10. See Appendix; Tables 6, 7, and 8 for underlying country-specific result.

  11. Technical change and underlying production technology of energy sectors are discussed in detail by Managi et al. (2004) and Kerstens and Managi (2012).

  12. See Diewert (1976) and Caves et al. (1982).

References

  1. Caves DW, Christensen LR, Diewert WE (1982) The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50:1393–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Ceglowski J, Golub S (2007) Just how low are China’s labour costs? World Econ 30:597–617. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9701.2007.01006.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Ceglowski J, Golub SS (2012) Does China still have a labor cost advantage? Glob Econ J. doi:10.1515/1524-5861.1874

    Google Scholar 

  4. Coelli TJ, Rao DSP, O’Donnel CJ, Batesse GE (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis. 2nd ed. Springer, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  5. Diewert WE (1976) Exact and superlative index numbers. J Econo 4:115–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Fisher I (1922) The making of index numbers: a study of their varieties, tests, and reliability. Houghton Mifflin, Boston, MA

    Google Scholar 

  7. Galí J, Gertler M. (1999) Inflation dynamics: a structural econometric analysis. J Monet Econ 44:195–222. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(99)00023-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Kerstens K, Managi S (2012) Total factor productivity growth and convergence in the petroleum industry: empirical analysis testing for convexity. Int J Prod Econ 139:196–206. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2012.04.008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Managi S, Opaluch JJ, Jin D, Grigalunas TA (2004) Technological change and depletion in offshore oil and gas. J Environ Econ Manage 47:388–409. doi:10.1016/S0095-0696(03)00093-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Mizobuchi H (2014) Returns to scale effect in labour productivity growth. J Product Anal 42:293–304. doi:10.1007/s11123-014-0408-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Sbordone AM (2002) Prices and unit labor costs: a new test of price stickiness. J Monet Econ 49:265–92. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(01)00111-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production function. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  13. Turner AG, Golub SS (1997) Towards a system of unit labor cost-based competitiveness indicators for advanced, developing and transition countries. Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, IMF, Washington, DC,á…ź

    Google Scholar 

  14. Turner P, Van’t dack J (1993) Measuring international price and cost competitiveness. Bank for International Settlements Economic Paper No. 39, Basel ᅟ

    Google Scholar 

  15. Van Ark B, Stuivenwold E, Ypma G (2005) Unit labour costs, productivity and international competitiveness. Research Memorandum GD-80, Groningen Growth and Development Centre

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful to Bert Balk, Michio Suzuki and the anonymous referee for their helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are the author’s responsibility. This article was completed when I visited the School of Economics at the University of Queensland. I appreciate the good research environment offered by the department. This research was financially supported by Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (KAKENHI 25870922).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hideyuki Mizobuchi.

Additional information

Competing interests

The author declares that he has no competing interests.

Underlying data and result for 18 countries

Underlying data and result for 18 countries

Table 3 Average growth rate of GDP, labor and factor prices, and average share of factor input from 1995 to 2006 (%), whole economy
Table 4 Average growth rate of GDP, labor and factor prices, and average share of factor input from 1995 to 2006 (%), manufacturing sector
Table 5 Average growth rate of GDP, labor and factor prices, and average share of factor input from 1995 to 2006 (%), electricity, gas, and water supply sector
Table 6 Decomposition of changes in unit labor cost from 1995 to 2006 (%), whole economy
Table 7 Decomposition of changes in unit labor cost from 1995 to 2006 (%), manufacturing sector
Table 8 Decomposition of changes in unit labor cost from 1995 to 2006 (%), electricity, gas, and water supply sector

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits use, duplication, adaptation, distribution, and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mizobuchi, H. Measuring the comprehensive wage effect of changes in unit labor cost. Economic Structures 4, 7 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-015-0017-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-015-0017-4

Keywords